DAWN - Opinion; April 17, 2003

Published April 17, 2003

Are we near take-off stage?

By Sultan Ahmed


PRESIDENT Pervez Musharraf has been stressing in recent weeks that as a result of the macro-economic stability Pakistan has come to the take-off stage. That means the country can sustain its economic growth largely through its own momentum, and not through continuous inflow of external aid with varied stipulations.

But that seems to be an exaggeration of the actual state of the economy, even judging by what the experts of the IMF and the World Bank have recently been saying. In fact, they are now considering to treat Pakistan more like a highly indebted poor country which, like African countries, qualifies for a write-off of much of its heavy debt and rescheduling of the rest of the debt, and deserves more loans for poverty reduction and social sector development.

Earlier in the 1990s we had tried to claim a HIPC status when over 20 African countries, ravaged by civil war and AIDS, were classified in that category. But their external debt was small compared to Pakistan’s larger debt. And we were told that we were more developed than the African countries living in abject poverty. But now because of our large population of whom around 40 per cent live below the poverty line the low economic growth in the 1990s and our falling per capita income, the joint staff of the IMF and World Bank evaluating our poverty reduction programme is inclined to consider Pakistan for the unenviable HIPC status.

But that is not what can attract foreign investors to Pakistan at a time when we have a target of 1.5 billion dollars of direct foreign investment next year following almost one billion dollar largely in the oil and gas sector as FDI this year. They want a fast growing economy to profit from and not an economy which goes in reverse direction to profit from debt write-off and cheaper loans. We should know what we want and move in that direction purposefully, instead of being tempted by any kind of relief offer from anywhere.

Prof. W.W. Rostow came up in 1960 with his book “The stages of Economic Growth” which he called a Non-Communist Manifesto and spoke of the five stages of economic growth beginning with the traditional society and ending with the take-off stage, as had happened in many western countries led by the US. The take-off stage can’t be a stop-go process but a self-fuelling steady one with self-correcting mechanisms. We are far from that stage now. We are a large traditional society economically, politically and socially with pockets of modernism or progress. Our vast tribal areas and feudal society testify to that. Our major industries are frequently facing a crisis. Take the textile industry, sugar industry, the engineering industry minus the automobile makers and our cement industry. Exceptions apart, most of such units appear to be in a crisis, with about 4,000 sick industrial units plaguing the economy most of the time. This is the reverse of the take-off stage.

We do not come to the take off stage when our national debt is 100 per cent of the GDP. At the moment the focus is more on reducing foreign debt which was earlier 61 per cent of the budget. Now it has come down to 46 per cent, says Gen. Musharraf and he hopes to bring that down to 30 per cent in two years. That is what will take us to the take off stage and not the heavy debt of 100 per cent of the GDP even after much of the foreign debt is re-scheduled.

Even now the focus is on external debt and not on the domestic debt which is about 50 per cent of the GDP. And we are not paying the domestic loans. Instead we are slashing the interest rates to the despair of the public or the savers. Even now the interest on domestic debt is Rs. 192 billion which is about 40 per cent of the tax revenues of the country. And yet the heavy domestic borrowing continues unabated as such loans are treated as unfunded or floating loans, repaid at one end and borrowed more at the other end.

A recent book “The Exclusive Quest for Growth” by William Easternly, who had been with the World Bank for 16 years, says foreign aid, foreign investment, education, family planning, big infrastructure, projects, conditional aid, debt forgiveness, etc. have not worked to produce what they had sought. All those activities are futile, he says, as long as a particular requirement is not met: definite political institutions are needed for development to be possible institutions such as rule of law and corruption-free government. It has been stressed what we need is not only macro-economic stability but also macro-political stability, which has always been the missing element in Pakistan.

Look at the might of tribal power or feudal fury as evidenced by the manner the gas mains were blown up again and again in Rajanpur and later in Bahawalpur. The imbecility of the government is demonstrated by the fact that even when the culprits are identified or their sponsors established they cannot be punished, and they and others prevented from repeating the same.

Without good governance, which means integrity of rulers, efficient administration and peace and justice for all, the best development schemes cannot be a success. That is what Gunner Myrdal spoke of in 1985 when he defined the “soft state,” which in our case is too soft at one end and violent at the other, while the new democratic structure has become a farce incapable of delivering anything to the masses and truly accelerating economic growth.

Palliatives like not increasing electric power rates at a time of falling world oil prices, or not retiring civilians from service while recruiting retired military officials for top jobs, or the Prime Minister asking senior officers not to behave like “Bara Sahabs” will not do. We need radical solutions for our endemic problems and the distress of the poor. The World Bank has mentioned how vulnerable are the poor in countries like Pakistan in its report on “Poverty and Vulnerability in South Asia.” Our rulers should make it their handbook if they really want to reduce the perennial distress of the poor and the new problems which confront them day after day.

The joint staff of the IMF and World Bank have identified four roadblocks to faster economic growth and reduction of poverty. They are political opposition to economic reforms, lack of continuity in economic policies and programmes, insufficient institutional capacity or exogenous or external shocks.

Centre-piece of the reforms is tax reforms which means higher taxes and larger tax collection and fewer or no tax exemptions, higher electricity rates and higher prices for gas and no or low support price for agricultural products. All that will add to the hardships of the poor by making the cost of living higher. Instead the people expect relief from the elected rulers, and not add to the levies of the military government.

Tax revenues can be increased by eliminating corruption from the ranks of the CBR which comes to about 40 per cent of the money paid by the people to the taxation officers. But fighting corruption among the taxation officials is an uphill task. So the IMF urges the government to come up with new taxes or spread the 15 per cent sales tax to new areas. It also wants about 55 tax exemptions given to various sectors of the economy to be withdrawn so that more revenues could be collected.

But if the taxes were not too many in number, and if there was less corruption among the CBR officials, and if the people were getting real returns for the taxes they pay, they may be willing to pay higher taxes or larger revenues. But these expectations are not being fulfilled by the government. Instead we have a bloated government with more of its officials behaving like “Bara Sahebs” and elected representatives are now paid double of what their predecessors were paid and have brand new cars. So the people are not willing to pay more taxes. The moral basis for higher taxation is not there after the elections as well as before that.

The right approach to pricing electric power is to cut the 40 per cent theft and loss of power in KESC and to a lower extent in the WAPDA region. But four years of military management of both the utilities has not resulted in notable reduction of the theft while the world oil prices kept on soaring. Hence the IMF and the World Bank keep on pressing both the utilities to raise their power rates and reduce their large deficits, which meets with resistance from the people. Hence Prime Minister Zafarullah Jamali is reported to have cancelled the orders of 12 to 18 paisa rise in the power rates, which will incense the IMF.

In such an environment there cannot be continuity in major policies that directly impinge on the people. In addition, we had four long periods of military rule in between political intervals. Political leaders too have tried to be different from each other in policy formulation and execution. Even change of ministers seems to make a difference in policies. Sometimes change of secretaries to the government also results in different policies.

When the rulers try to do too much with too little, the net result is bound to be confusion or stagnation. The political immaturity of or political leaders and the large promises they make before the elections despite the scant resources are responsible for our political failures or later popular rejection of their leaders.

Insufficient institutional capacity is also held responsible for our economic setbacks. When the wrong men are heading the departments or they know too little about the intricacies of administration, or if the secretaries to the government get changed as frequently as they do in Sindh insufficient institutional capacity is inevitable.

In addition there is the pervasive corruption, political as well as bureaucratic, which results in the squandering of the scarce resources. This is all the more so in respect of funds spent on the agricultural sector, including irrigation. When youngsters are made ministers and the utterly inexperienced are made chief ministers without the requisite education or expertise the institutions they head are bound to be ineffective and replete with corruption. To add to that, there is the over-staffing in many departments which results in red tape or larger corruption.

The exogenous shocks of which IMF and World Bank staff talk have been plenty. In 1998 there were the nuclear explosions followed by economic sanctions, in 1999 the Kargil episode and then the military take-over and the sanctions, in 2001 the September 11 tragedy and then the fall of the Taliban regime in Kabul, in 2002 concentration of troops by India on our borders, and in 2003 the war on Iraq. All these events had their major impact on us and affected our economic growth and poverty reduction.

Do we need more land reforms?

By Mahmood Hasan Khan


TWO years ago Shahrukh Rafi Khan and four of his colleagues at the Sustainable Development Policy Institute (SDPI) wrote a paper for the late Omar Asghar Khan — who was then a federal minister — “The Case for Land and Agrarian Reforms in Pakistan”: SDPI Policy Brief Series No. 12. They thought that these structural reforms were needed as an end and a means to reduce rural poverty. It seems that the policy brief has had no hearing so far in the corridors of power.

On the contrary, some in power now say that these reforms are not needed. Their answer to the question I have submitted is a plain No. The reason given is equally simple: if something is not broken, why repair it? The assertion is that the existing system of landownership and control neither interferes with the efficient use of land nor contributes to the existing inequalities and poverty. Luckily this assertion is empirically verifiable, but there are serious problems with the data on landownership and land use.

Let me make a few general observations first. To say that there is no jagirdari and no jagirdars in Pakistan is technically correct. However, seen in another perspective, this is a factually incorrect statement since jagirdari and jagirdars are not emotive metaphors but an important part of the social and economic reality in Pakistan. Land is an important asset in the economy for income and power.

One of the major causes of rural poverty is landlessness and near-landlessness. This applies particularly to those rural households in which the workers have no skills or education and the industrial-urban nexus is weak. Landlessness results largely from the process of depeasantization or agricultural progress embedded in the capitalist mode: fewer people are needed on the land and fewer (small) landowners can survive, thanks to the changes in markets, technology, population, and public policy. Progress and poverty can thus coexist for a long time in the transition if nothing else is done.

Returning to the issue of landownership and control in Pakistan, one can safely say that landownership matters to both income and power: the more (good quality) land one has the more income and power one can enjoy at the community and state level. Landownership confers certain rights to other assets that the landless cannot claim. Nor is it all.

If a lot of land is owned and controlled by a small proportion of the community, it allows the landowners to subjugate the landless through patronage and force with or without the help of state machinery. It can help maintain the patron-client relationship and deny a large section of the community its fundamental right to human dignity and freedom.

It has been said earlier that the basic issue is empirically verifiable. The problem is that we are constrained by the dearth of numbers on landownership and control. The data on landownership are kept by the revenue officials, but are not available to the public in a usable form. Second, the land record in each revenue circle shows landownership by individuals. But an individual may own land in more than one place. Also, one family (household) may own large chunks of land, but we cannot verify this fact easily from the individual land record. Finally, landowners rent in and rent out land, affecting their control of land and tenants.

We can get a good idea of changes in the usufruct of land from the agriculture census reports. The problem is that the data from the censuses and land records separately are not helpful. We have to use them together to get a reasonably fair idea of the extent of land concentration by ownership and use and the state of tenancy arrangements. What is more important is that even when we have the data from these two sources we cannot address the issues of landlessness and the rights of (sharecropping) tenants. Sample surveys can do this job fairly well.

Let me say bluntly that the intellectual and research community in Pakistan has not given the needed attention to these empirical issues. Like others, most researchers and intellectuals keep on using the anecdotal and partial — not necessarily credible — information and data on landownership and control in Pakistan.

The other issue is of the relationship of landownership and control with farm efficiency and distribution of income. Luckily, some good evidence exists that we can have efficient agriculture on small parcels of land owned and cultivated by landowners provided certain conditions are met, including access to finance, technology, fair markets of inputs and outputs, support services, and infrastructure. The economic incentives to small landowners, when a high proportion of the land is owned and controlled by a minority of owners, are often not adequate for realizing their productive potential.

The large landowners tend to get preferential access to markets, finance, public support services, and much else. The sharecropping tenants — whose numbers are declining rather rapidly in Pakistan — are particularly at a disadvantage. Their subjugation by the landowner, supported often by the state, through debt creates little incentive for risk-taking or investment. The rights of tenants, limited though they are in law, are almost always a victim of the way in which the administrative and judicial institutions function. There is no organized party of these peasants powerful enough to mediate on their behalf.

Recent changes in the agrarian structure of Pakistan have been dominated by the rapid landlessness of small landowners and sharecropping tenants. Their alienation from land and conversion into wage-labour is a major source of rural poverty and rapid migration to towns and cities. They cannot survive without human capital or skills simply on uncertain employment in rural areas in particular. Corporatization of farming without institutional reforms in the agrarian system is likely to exacerbate the problems of landlessness and unemployment, creating wealth for some and poverty for many others.

There is evidence that the concentration of land and rural income has not fallen and rural poverty has increased, particularly in the last decade. Also, there is evidence that agricultural production in Pakistan has been rising as a result of the increased level of inputs and not increased productivity of resources.

If one explores the reasons for these observations, one finds that land concentration, unprotected sharecropping tenancy, landlessness, bad water management, deterioration in the quality of agricultural land, and the poor quality of social and physical infrastructure are the major elements.

Finally, public policy and its implementation matter very much. It is also important to realize that public policy and its implementation reflect mainly the ideology and interests of groups that own and control the major assets in society. It is often in their interest to form coalitions rather than compete against each other since the former allows higher returns to each interest group. These coalitions are clearly reflected in the political regime no matter how many times its label changes. The agenda of these coalitions changes very little.

Christians in education

A letter captioned “Return of F.C. College” in this newspaper a couple of weeks ago, about restoration of one of Lahore’s premier colleges to its original owners, let loose a flood of memories, not least of the days when the college was situated at Nila Gumbad, right in the heart of the city.

I had failed to clear my F.Sc. there and was so depressed at the thought of going to the dusty, barren new site on the canal to do my Second Year all over again that I ran away from the college. (It’s a long story, to be left to another time).

After recalling the correspondent’s worry that, on reversion to the Presbyterian Church, the authorities of F.C. College might increase the fees and other charges under the so-called Self- Financing Scheme, and thus make it difficult for middle-class students to join the college, let me say that I have been interested in the matter ever since PM Zulfikar Ali Bhutto nationalised hundreds of Christian (and many Muslim) educational institutions in 1972. I was in Punjab Information at that time and I remember with what dismay we viewed the decision.

The only plausible reason cited by Mr Bhutto was that the managers of these institutions — Christian and Muslim religious societies — did not pay government grades to the teaching and other staff and were exploiting them. This was not incorrect, and many of them (even Christian teachers) were jubilant at the take- over on this score. But that could have been easily remedied by making the societies do so by law, instead of turning dedicated schools and colleges into dens of bureaucratic lethargy.

I clearly recall the comments of some newspapers at that time which, though opposed to the PPP and Mr Bhutto, welcomed the nationalisation of Christian missionary schools because, as they said, the students would no longer be fed on heretic ideas. I don’t know what they had to say when they found that the government of the NWFP, then headed by Maulana Mufti Mahmud of the JUI as chief minister, had refused to implement the centre’s directive to take over the Christian schools and colleges in Peshawar and elsewhere. The actual take-over was to be done by the provinces because education was a provincial subject.

I visited F.C. College a few years after the take-over, and found it bereft of those special qualities, that atmosphere of academic absorption, that determination of the staff to teach (whatever the circumstances) which had been the hallmark of my Alma Mater. Now it was just like any other government college in any other city of Punjab, and certainly not like the famous Government College of Lahore which still bears some traces of its pre-partition character.

There was the usual lack of students’ respect for studies and the faculty, which the latter paid back in the form of carelessness and irregularity in attendance. I suppose the same could be said about the fate of other taken-over institutions. I remember saying to a friend after the visit that, although an old boy of the college, I would hate to be its principal.

During these long years after Mr Bhutto’s educational coup, I have noticed a strange contradiction in the attitude of the people towards Christian schools and colleges opened afterwards. I had the dubious pleasure of listening to some speeches in the National Assembly a few years ago on the difference about perception of Islam between students of schools run by the Islamic Republic and those of privately managed English-medium schools. The indignant members wanted the difference to be removed, although from what I have seen of my grandchildren studying in a modern, fashionable school, they know more about Islam than the children of government schools.

In keeping with our national standard of hypocrisy, you will find the boys and girls of these MNAs all going to English-medium schools or those latterly started by Christians with a long involvement with education. Of course some of them who are extra- anxious that at least their sons should be brought up in a religious Islamic atmosphere, send them to foreign lands — Britain or America — so that they can develop into citizens imbued with the Pakistan ideology and love of their faith!

So far as my knowledge of societal conditions in the small and medium-sized towns of Punjab goes, the rising middle class, far removed from Lahore or the other big cities, is obsessed by the belief that generally Christians make good and hard-working teachers. You may find it hard to believe, but I want to tell you a bizarre fact. Some Muslim school managers who find education a paying commercial investment, name their schools after Christian saints. So, parents eager to provide English-based instruction to their wards, flock to these schools, without bothering to enquire about the antecedents of the administration!

All these were incidental observations. Now I come to the nub of this piece. On getting cold feet when some religious elements and students owing allegiance to Islamic political parties threatened demonstrations against the release of the taken-over institutions, the Punjab administration of the pre-October period actually succumbed to pressure and the Governor promised angry delegations that the restoration was being shelved. Since the supreme Court had held in 1995 that the F.C. College belonged to the Presbyterian Church, I wonder what would have happened if someone had moved that court to charge the government with contempt.

Anyway the present government decided to take the bull by the horns and went through the necessary steps to hand over F.C. College to its old owners. A number of guarantees and assurances have been held out to teachers for protecting their service and salaries and to students that no one already on the college rolls will be required to pay enhanced fees. Now the commonsense approach would be that if a teacher or a student feels it a moral burden to continue his association with the college, he should be welcome to snap it.

One hopes that similar firm decisions will be taken by the Punjab government in respect of Lahore’s prestigious Kinnaird College for Women and Rawalpindi’s Gordon College and Sialkot’s Murray College. By the way, religious elements in Punjab have never considered it odd that Allama Iqbal, the leader of Muslim renaissance in the subcontinent and the philosopher behind the demand for Pakistan, was educated in Murray College. Incidentally, so was Faiz Ahmed Faiz who, beside other subjects, studied Arabic there, and finally did his M.A. in that language from the Punjab University.

Now that the process of nationalisation is being reversed, somebody should write a book on the contribution of Christian missionaries to the education of Muslim youth in this region.

Iraq contracts

AS Iraq goes from a military to a financial battleground, billions of taxpayer dollars are at stake. Congress is stepping in to ensure that rebuilding doesn’t turn into cronyism for big business. Even the appearance of impropriety by the Pentagon and the US Agency for International Development in awarding bids could sully the US effort to turn Iraq into a functioning democracy.

Already, three members of House of Representatives are calling for a General Accounting Office investigation of whether Halliburton Co., which was headed by Vice President Dick Cheney for five years before he resigned in August 2000, received special treatment from the Pentagon in securing a contract.

There’s no evidence that Cheney influenced the contract. Still, as The Times’ Mark Fineman and Dana Calvo reported Sunday, many are suspicious about how Halliburton subsidiary Kellogg Brown & Root, in alliance with Houston-based Boots & Coots International Well Control, locked in a no-bid, two-year contract worth up to $7 billion for suppressing oil well fires.

Waxman and Dingell are also calling for an investigation of eight contracts awarded by the USAID. — Los Angeles Times

The conflict has just begun

WHEN in February, 1258 the killing had stopped and the looting had paused, Hulagu, grandson of the creator of the world’s prevailing superpower Chengiz Khan, and the destroyer of the 37-Caliph Abbasid dynasty, asked the Iraqi ulema, or religious heads, a simple question: “Which man is better as a sovereign? An unbeliever who is just, or a Muslim who is unjust?”

The question is not substantially different from the one posed to the people of Iraq by George Bush, son of the victor of the first Gulf war and undisputed leader of the prevailing superpower. The 13th century clerics were silent until one of the sages in their midst, Radiuddin Ali, accepted new realities and wrote down the collective answer: “The unbeliever who is just should be preferred to the unjust believer.”

It would be convenient to report that this is where the matter ended. But there was more than one answer given by the Arabs, and delivered over time. Not one of these responses ever suggested that the deposed and killed last Abbasid Caliph Mustaffim be restored to the palaces of Baghdad. That era was dead, killed by its own excesses and buried by the Mongol avalanche, and the Arabs recognized it. But to reject the Abbasids was not synonymous with accepting the Mongols.

The Mongols promised that the new regime in Baghdad would be run by Iraqis, not by them. They too established the difference between control and administration. The former lay with Hulagu and his generals. The latter was left to the Iraqis. Hulagu retained Ibn Alkamiya as the vizier, or the prime minister, who had served the last Caliph. Till today Arab schoolchildren are taught the sentence: “Cursed by God be he who curses not Ibn Alkamiya.”

Hulagu’s armies were not without Muslims in their ranks when he marched on Baghdad, although they were not too many. His few Muslim supporters were Shias, not Kurds: Kurds then had total empathy with the fellow Sunni Arabs, for the ruling dynasty of Saladin was indeed Kurdish. Some of the Muslim support for Hulagu was destroyed by guilt, as was the case of Teghel Argun who slipped away from the Mongol ranks after witnessing the destruction of Baghdad. He was later captured by the Mongols and put to death in the marketplace of Tabriz.

Many of the regional Muslim lords became submissive to the new power. Azizuddin Kavus offered Hulagu a magnificent pair of leather boots as a gift. He also had his own portrait drawn on the boots so that Hulagu could have him permanently at his feet.

Yet others tried craft. The old and wily Badruddin Lulu of Mosul, on being summoned to Hulagu’s presence, promised his terrified followers that he would emerge with his honour intact. In fact, he suggested, he would not return before he had gone so far as to tweak Hulagu’s ears! He lived up to his promise. He offered Hulagu a magnificent pair of rare pearls and then asked for the honour of placing them on the conqueror’s ears. He was granted permission to do so. He tweaked Hulagu’s ears when putting on the earrings, and glanced at his entourage while doing so to indicate that he had kept his promise.

But there were also those who responded to the deepest crisis in the history of Islam by discovering conviction, and then the courage to stand up against a power that since Chengiz Khan had never been defeated between the eastern shores of China to the doors of western Europe beyond Russia, and now to the heart of the Muslim world in Baghdad.

Then, as now, the fall of Baghdad opened the way to Damascus and Syria. Then, as now, the temptation seemed irresistible. Nassir, sultan of Damascus, played for time, sending his son to Hulagu with the excuse that he could not come personally because he feared that in his absence the Crusaders would march on Damascus. Hulagu was unimpressed by the explanation. He sent Nassir a message, the essence of which was: “Know that we are God’s army on earth.” He, like others after him, saw his conquest as a moral purpose. “Those who oppose us must flee, and we must hunt them... Resist, and face annihilation. Accept, and find safety. Accept our law, so that our laws can be common... Answer quickly, or your country will be turned into a desert.”

Nassir’s reply was braver than the strength of his forces warranted. He said, “Resistance to you is obedience to God... If we slay you, our prayers have been answered. If you slay us, we go to Paradise.”

Hulagu had no desire to come in between Nassir and Paradise. On September 12, 1259, some 19 months after the destruction of Baghdad, he marched into Syria. The story began on a familiar note, with the successive destruction of cities culminating in the annihilation of Aleppo in January 1260. Nassir, betrayed and depressed, abandoned Damascus, but remained in the field. This was sufficient, for behind him a resurrection was taking place, inspired by a Turkish slave regiment of the Egyptian armies, called the Mamelukes.

This regiment had picked up the Egyptian battle standard at the point of collapse and defeat against the Crusaders, reversed the western tide, re-established the confidence of Cairo, and was now ready to face, under the leadership of a great general like Baibers, towards the threat from the east. Hulagu was marching not merely through territory; he was also trampling through the shifting sands of Arab politics and faith.

Aleppo was his last victory. Most interestingly, he was interrupted by an election.

He got news that Mangu, the Great Khan and overlord of the Mongols, had died. He turned towards home to establish his own claim in the Ordu, a gathering where family and chiefs elected the successor by consensus. At Tabriz Hulagu learnt that his brother Kublai Khan had already been named the successor. He halted. But in that respite, equations had changed. The Mongol general he had left in charge, Kita Buga, had moved towards Palestine to take Jerusalem from the Muslims.

But on September 3, 1260, at Ain Jalut, near Nablus in Palestine, the Egyptians delivered a crushing blow on the Mongols, shattering their armies and demolishing their myth of invincibility. Damascus was retaken, and the Mongols pursued and scattered from Arab territories. But the war was not over. Hulagu would not accept defeat. But neither, now, would the Arabs. The defence of El Biret in Syria in the winter of 1264 is part of the romance of Arab history: significantly, the women proved themselves more courageous than the men.

In another fascinating twist, Hulagu’s brother, Berkai, leader of the Mongols in Russia, suddenly announced in an open letter that he and his four brothers had converted to Islam. He charged Hulagu with the destruction of Baghdad and in cooperation with Baibers, he sent an army under Nogai, through the Caucasus, which defeated Hulagu on January 13, 1263. Hulagu spent his last days in Persia until he died on February 8, 1265, at the age of 48.

History, of course, does not repeat itself. There may be parallels, but nothing is ever a replica. Saddam is far less than the last of the Abbasids, and the Arabs do not seem to be in any condition to find a Baibers, let alone a Berkai. (It would need Putin to intervene decisively in the region for the parallel to start working.)

It would be a mistake to romanticize the decline and disappearance of Saddam Hussein. He was more clever than powerful. He exploited Arab anger against neo-colonialism (oil and nationalism are virtually synonymous in the Arab world). But Saddam, being a tyrant, was a problem rather than a solution. The consequences are familiar to those who read history. A crisis has eliminated the pretender, and the future waits to see who will fill this vacuum.

The Americans want this space to be occupied by a favourite like Ahmad Chalabi. But all they will succeed in doing is setting up an administration. There is a difference between administration and control. A figurehead may sit in Baghdad, but George Bush will be in power. This was precisely the situation after the First World War, when a British-Indian army ‘liberated’ Iraq from the Ottomans and imposed first direct, and then indirect rule. The British foreign secretary in 1918, Sir Arthur Balfour, was not concerned about niceties. He said: “I do not care under what system we keep the oil. But I am quite clear that it is all-important for us that this oil should be available.”

Iraqi nationalism, supported by Arab anger, will also seek to fill that vacuum.

A second mistake is also being made by the victors. Attempts to divide and rule have begun. In India it was Hindus and Muslims; in Iraq it will be Shias and Sunnis and Kurds. The Kurds want this division because they have been offered the dream of independence; but a Shia-Sunni divide will not be equally simple.

The story of Sheikh Abdel Majid al-Khoei may not be definitive, but it is a marker. The 50-year-old Shia cleric, head of the London-based Khoei Foundation and well respected in his community, was despatched by the British to Najaf to generate the support for the invasion that seemed to be strangely missing in Basra and Karbala and Najaf and Umm Qasr. On Monday, April 7, Sheikh Majid called upon Shias to support the Americans and the British. On Tuesday he suggested neutrality. On Thursday he was killed in the Imam Ali mosque. Tony Blair sent a message of condolence.

The writer is editor-in-chief of Asian Age based in New Delhi.

Opinion

Editorial

Paying the price
Updated 18 Apr, 2025

Paying the price

Pakistan is trapped in a relentless cycle of climate volatility.
Political solution
18 Apr, 2025

Political solution

THOUGH the BNP-M may have ended its 20-day protest sit-in outside Quetta on Wednesday, the core issues affecting...
Grave desecration
18 Apr, 2025

Grave desecration

THE desecration of 85 Muslim graves at a cemetery in Hertfordshire in the UK is a distressing act that deserves the...
Double-edged sword
Updated 17 Apr, 2025

Double-edged sword

While remittances have provided critical support to current account, they have also been a double-edged sword.
Besieged people
17 Apr, 2025

Besieged people

DESPITE all the talk about becoming a ‘hard’ state, Pakistan is still looking incredibly soft when it comes to...
Deadly zealotry
Updated 17 Apr, 2025

Deadly zealotry

Murdering people and attacking firms is indefensible and only besmirches the Palestinian cause.