Two nations, two armies
The sociologist Charles Tilly famously compared modern states to organised crime, arguing that they are essentially protection rackets. In return for revenue and support, states protect citizens from external actors, and also provide internal stability and security through the provision of public goods including law enforcement. However, as Tilly pointed out, wars and antagonistic external relationships are usually instigated and sustained by states themselves, and that the mechanisms that underpin domestic security could easily be turned against a populace, either through direct coercion (using, for example, the police) or by withholding vital services and, indeed, liberties. Hundreds of years of contestation between rulers and the ruled, the gradual emergence of democracy, and the transformation of subjects into citizens, may now constrain the arbitrary exercise of power by the state, particularly in the advanced industrial democracies, but Tilly’s main point remains valid: all states are founded on violence, and it is their capacity to exercise it that gives them power. Ultimately, states protect citizens from themselves.
It is not coincidental that the vast majority of coups and military dictatorships that emerged in the second half of the 20th century (and those that continue to exist today) occurred in former colonies. As the wealth of literature on this area demonstrates, many post-colonial states were saddled with a legacy of poorly institutionalised civilian politics coming up against the power of well-developed militaries. Colonial regimes, driven as they were by the imperatives of maintaining order and engaging in accumulation, invested a tremendous amount of effort into creating effective and efficient bureaucracies and militaries that could function without being hampered by indigenous, democratic oversight. This contrasted with the anaemic growth of representative politics; as and when it did materialise in the colonised world, ‘democracy’ was usually little more than window-dressing, designed to perpetuate colonial control while deepening extant divisions in society and cementing the power of local, elite collaborators. As such, when independence was finally achieved, many anti-colonial nationalist movements struggling to assert control over their new nations found themselves having to deal with militaries that possessed the means to displace them in the ‘national interest’. That these militaries themselves defined what the ‘national interest’ was, and also bestowed the responsibility for upholding it upon themselves, only served to support Tilly’s point about states, violence, and protection.
Steven I. Wilkinson’s work on the Indian military and democracy presents a comprehensive view of the political divergence between India and Pakistan
History is not always destiny, however, with this being amply demonstrated in Steven Wilkinson’s Army and Nation: The Military and Indian Democracy Since Independence. Professor Wilkinson teaches political science at Yale, and has long been one of the most astute observers and analysts of contemporary Indian politics. In this book, he turns his attention to a classic question that has been of considerable interest to those studying South Asia: given their similar institutional and colonial legacies, why was India able to democratise even as Pakistan slid further and further into military authoritarianism? After all, given the generally dismal record many former colonies have had in this regard, India’s democratic trajectory was far from guaranteed. This was perhaps especially true given that the Raj in India possessed a formidable military whose professionalism, expertise, and organisational coherence could have allowed it to assert itself as a dominant political player in a context where post-colonial India’s ethnic and religious tensions could have potentially bred the type of instability that usually precedes authoritarian interventions. Indeed, this is arguably exactly what happened in Pakistan, when ethnic conflict between the eastern and western wings, coupled with incompetence and factional infighting amongst the political elite, facilitated the military’s eventual, and perhaps inevitable, entry into politics just a decade after Independence.
For Wilkinson, the answer to the question of why the military did not intervene in politics or, rather, how it was reigned in, has three different components. The first peg of the argument deals with the varying inheritances of Pakistan and India. Here, Army and Nation treads relatively familiar ground as it echoes arguments made by Ayesha Jalal and others about how the economic strategic situation Pakistan inherited in 1947 prompted the prioritisation of military and defence needs above all others. From the very outset, Pakistan had to deal with the fact that it had to secure and defend its potentially dangerous and volatile borders with India and Afghanistan. What this entailed in practice was the channelling of resources into the development of the armed forces, with up to 70 per cent of the budget going to defence in the years following Partition, as well as the cultivation of alliances with the United States and others in order to gain weapons and economic assistance. This latter factor was crucial given that Pakistan’s economic base — lacking industry and revenue generating potential — was insufficient to effectively cater to the new country’s military priorities. In a context where the military was already relatively well-developed (in comparison with civilian political entities), the emphasis on defence only served to further enhance its capacities.
India, on the other hand, suffered from few of these problems. In addition to having an economy that was on a much healthier footing, India did not suffer from the same security concerns as its western neighbour. This, in turn, helped in facilitating a policy of non-alignment that allowed India to maintain a relatively independent foreign policy that, crucially, kept it away from the decision-making process when it came to external affairs.
For Wilkinson, however, the difference between the economic and strategic constraints faced by newly independent Pakistan and India provides only part of the explanation for why the military grew to be so much more powerful in the former. Of greater importance is the way in which recruitment into the military from the so-called ‘martial races’ skewed political outcomes in the two countries. Under the British Raj, strategic imperatives and colonial anthropology fused to create the idea of the ‘martial races’; it was believed that the inhabitants of Punjab and what was then known as the North-Western Frontier Province (NWFP) were natural warriors whose martial prowess justified their disproportionate recruitment into the Indian army. As a result, by the 1940s, almost half the total members of the Indian army were drawn from Punjab, and over 60 pc were drawn from the demographically narrow pool of ‘martial races’. At Partition, however, this equation changed with tremendous repercussions for both India and Pakistan; the division of the subcontinent meant that Pakistan inherited nearly all the areas that had traditionally supplied recruits to the Indian army, meaning that it now possessed an army overwhelmingly dominated by Punjabis, while India moved to a situation where the share of Punjab in the armed forces was reduced by almost half.
“The reasons for India’s success in civil-military relations despite the absence of massive ethnic restructuring were, first, the federal and broad-based character of the Congress Party and a series of crucial decisions the party took from 1947 to 1953 to abolish religious electorates and religious reservations, allow linguistic reorganisation of India’s states, and enable caste reservations.” — Excerpt from the book
The demographic composition of the two armies had important consequences; the ethnic homogeneity of the Pakistani army meant that it would essentially come to be seen as being representative of a hegemonic Punjabi project within Pakistan, with this perception being exacerbated by the fact that Bengal and Sindh were two of the most marginal provinces in undivided India when it came to military recruitment. The problem was made worse by the fact that the uniformity of the military membership in Pakistan fostered and facilitated the organisational coherence that underpinned the planning and execution of successful coups.