According to Wilkins, the urban middle classes react to this and are often at the forefront of movements against populist governments. But even when these movements succeed in removing the government, the removal is often replaced by the return of the ruling elite which was sidelined by the hated populists. Ironically, the middle classes, too, are against the elite but eventually agree to accept it as a ‘lesser evil.’
Wilkins suggests that all mainstream political parties, whether on the left or on the right, eventually converge at the centre. This centrist position makes them complacent and stagnant. In such situations, populists may emerge from outside or from within these parties with rhetoric against the system.
They are roundly denounced as being pro-rich and anti-poor. Wilkins concludes that this frequently happens in developing countries but has now returned to haunt Europe and the US as well.
It would have been interesting had Wilkins also studied the history of populism in India and Pakistan because I believe a whole new model of populism is developing here which is different to the model constructed by Wilkins. Indeed, in the 1970s, populism in India and Pakistan was also derived by appealing to the sentiments of the have-nots and by demonising the economic and political elite. The Z.A. Bhutto regime did in Pakistan what the Indira Gandhi government did in India.
Also, both were, by and large, opposed by the urban middle-classes through movements which ousted them. The Indian middle class then had to sit through a rather disappointing experiment with the anti-Indira Janata Party, while the Pakistani middle class had to compromise by accepting the return of the elite in the shape of an anti-populist and conservative dictatorship (Zia).
However, the two massive electoral victories of India’s Hindu nationalist party, the BJP, in the country’s last two elections, and the coming to power of Imran Khan’s populist PTI in Pakistan, did not happen on the behest of the have-nots as such. Yes, both Modi and Khan’s rhetoric demonised the established political parties — the Congress, the PML-N and the PPP. Yet, both hardly ever used the other portion of the populist rhetoric which directly appeals to the poor. Instead, the demonisation of opponents and their ‘corruption’ was coupled by imagery of a country which mostly attracts the desires and imagination of India and Pakistan’s urban middle classes.
In most European countries and in the US, renegade members of the old elite are cleverly exploiting an exhausted political system to stir the emotions of the have-nots. But these populists are not quite as appealing to the middle classes. So the Wilkins model is relatable there.
But not so in today’s Pakistan and India, where the urban middle-classes have agreed to a secret handshake with state institutions, high society and the economic elite to construct its own form of populism — but one which does not include images of the ‘masses’ thronging around empathetic messiahs.
Indeed, both Modi and Imran too have been branded as messiahs, but by and for a class which, till the late 1990s, abhorred populism because it soiled its idea of decent politics, offended its morality and even threatened its economic position.
The establishment and segments of the economic elite, weary of populists stirring working-class sentiments, eventually came together with the frustrated urban middle classes to mould a new kind of populist — the middle-class demagogue.
Published in Dawn, EOS, June 2nd, 2019